//This page has been developed by B. Haesler, RVC//\\ \\ ====== 1. The economic evaluation of surveillance in relation to intervention and disease mitigation ====== \\ In the three variable relationship of disease mitigation, surveillance and intervention, the latter two can either be economic **complements** or **substitutes**. Surveillance and intervention resources as **complements** means that they always go together in a given ratio and can be considered to be one input, for example as seen in a testing (surveillance) and culling (intervention) strategy. Surveillance and intervention as **substitutes** means that using more of one input will allow the use of less resources for the other to achieve the same loss avoidance. The most prominent example here is early warning surveillance that aims to enable early response and containment of disease.\\ For optimal efficiency, the //combined// cost of surveillance and intervention should be minimised for a given disease mitigation objective. A disease mitigation objective is typically expressed as a reduction in prevalence or incidence (e.g. “reduce prevalence of disease x in population y by 10%”, “eradicate disease from population z”); both are technical measures of disease occurrence. If the value of loss avoidance is of interest (e.g. in a cost-benefit analysis), such prevalence or incidence reduction must be translated into the corresponding economic values of loss avoidance ([[http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1746-692X.2012.00233.x/abstract|Häsler and Howe 2012]]).\\ Any given level of value losses avoided may be obtained from different combinations of surveillance and intervention effort. In general, allocating more resources to surveillance should lead to better information about a disease threat which allows more targeted intervention. For example, identification of holdings or areas infected or at risk of disease, allows focusing treatment on those populations instead of choosing a blanket approach. Similarly, detecting a disease early through surveillance enables intervening at a point when the losses due to animal disease and disease spread are still limited, and resources required to tackle cases are lower than later in an outbreak.\\ For any disease of interest, it is therefore necessary to consider the technical trade-offs between surveillance and intervention that lead to distinct levels of loss avoidance, as described in detail elsewhere ([[http://journals.cambridge.org/action/displayAbstract?fromPage=online&aid=8776951&fileId=S095026881200060X|Howe, Häsler, and Stärk 2013]]). Figure 1 summarises the key principle: curves A1 and A2 represent two hypothetical levels of loss avoidance, which can be achieved by multiple combinations of surveillance and intervention. They illustrate the possibility of substitution between surveillance and intervention for two out of potentially very many feasible levels of avoided losses. The loss avoidance in curve A2 can be achieved by either doing a lot of surveillance and limited intervention (S* and I*) or limited surveillance and a lot of intervention (S° and I°).\\ \\ {{ :files:fig1.png?nolink&600 |}}\\ **Figure 1: The curves A1 and A2 describe two defined levels of loss avoidance (where A1 C every year of the project. \\ **Strengths**\\ \\ * NPV tells you how much money you gain, over and above your minimum cut off (the discount rate) * BCR is unaffected by project size * IRR gives you your average annual % return over the life of the project, a neat measure. It means you can be less definite about what your cut-off or minimum acceptable % return is = the discount rate. Both NPV and BCR depend on the discount rate. \\ ===== 2.3.3 Quantifying surveillance benefits ===== The important concept of loss avoidance is illustrated here with an example of early warning surveillance, where detecting disease early is expected to lead to a more rapid response (e.g. implementation of outbreak control measures) relative to the time of occurrence of the index case. Earlier in the outbreak, the losses already generated by the disease are smaller than at a later time. As a consequence, less spread means that the costs of intervention measures required are smaller than later in the outbreak with more animals and/or holdings being affected (Figure 3).\\ \\ {{ :files:fig3_.png?nolink |}} **Figure 3: Comparison of two surveillance options (S1 and S2) and their associated interventions (I1 and I2) in a situation where S2 leads to earlier detection of disease and I2 to effective disease control. The hatched area represents the losses avoided with the more effective combination of S2 and I2.** \\ \\ To estimate the value of losses avoided, it is necessary to identify the effects in the animals or holdings affected as well as the effect of potential externalities. The losses can then be estimated by multiplying the number of animals of a certain type or species (e.g. dairy cows) suffering from a disease impact (e.g. reduction in milk yield) by the lost physical production coefficient (e.g. rate of reduced milk yield in dairy cows) and the price coefficient related to the disease impact (e.g. production price per litre cow milk). All disease effects need to be “translated” from a technical perspective into a value perspective in this way and summed up. The resulting difference in losses between two strategies is the benefit. \\ \\ For surveillance that aims to detect cases of a specified condition in order to implement an intervention, the same logic applies. Figure 4 illustrates two levels of surveillance with their associated interventions for three different baselines of decreasing, stable and increasing prevalence. In each case, the surveillance and intervention costs need to be estimated and compared to the estimated associated loss avoidance to determine the economic efficiency of the mitigation strategy. The strategy to be preferable from an economic point of view is the strategy that creates the largest net benefit, i.e. where the (positive) difference between loss avoidance and combined surveillance and intervention costs is largest.\\ \\ {{ :files:fig4.png?nolink |}} **Figure 4: Comparison of two surveillance options and their associated interventions (S1&I1 and S2&I2) in a situation where the mitigation option 1 leads to disease reduction and the mitigation option 2 to disease elimination. A-c represent different baseline scenarios with decreasing, stable and increasing prevalence. The grey and hatched areas represent the losses avoided when the new strategies are compared to the baseline.** \\ \\ Because the impact of surveillance cannot be measured directly as a mitigation outcome, it is only possible to quantify the loss avoidance resulting from the combination of surveillance and intervention and to compare it to the expenditures for surveillance and intervention. Therefore, it is recommended to calculate a residual margin over intervention cost which constitutes the maximum additional expenditures potentially available for surveillance without the net benefit from mitigation overall becoming zero. This margin can then be compared to the expenditures of various surveillance options and the one maximising the net benefit would be the best from an economic point of view. An illustration of this concept can be found in Häsler et al. (2012).\\ \\ Using intermediate outcome proxy measures for the benefit (e.g. number of cases detected) for inclusion in a cost-effectiveness analysis is only justifiable when a clear correlation between the intermediate outcome and the benefit is firmly established through empirical research. Otherwise, the case detection capacity of a surveillance system is non-interpretable from an economic point of view. A logic model can help to establish the relationships between intermediate and final outcomes. For example (Figure 5):\\ \\ {{ :files:fig5.png?nolink |}} **Figure 5: A schematic logic model to illustrate the steps that leads from surveillance to a reduction of foodborne illness in humans.** \\ \\ In the example depicted in Figure 5, if the aim of mitigation is to avoid human cases (the value of such avoidance can be quantified) and only the case detection capacity of surveillance is to be assessed and compared to the costs of the surveillance, the link between the intermediate outcome (disease detection) and the final outcome (reduction in human cases) needs to be established.\\